Public-Private Partnerships in Roads

Road Concessions, BOTs, DBOs

An underdeveloped road network can contribute to sub-optimal economic performance and quality of life. While there has been significant investment in road networks globally, it is expected that very significant investments will continue to be required in the next 20 years to meet increasing demand arising from population growth and economic development. Recent studies indicate that both the investment requirement and the potential funding gap in road infrastructure will be significantly higher than other transportation sectors. In most jurisdictions this will mean building brand new roads, extending existing roads or both.

The nature of road projects varies considerably from project to project and is driven by the local, national or even international factors that make the project a necessity in the first place. New roads are expensive and governments are often constrained in their ability to commit fiscal spending to roads. This is an area where project financing and BOT projects are becoming more and more common.

As in other transportation subsectors, the allocation of demand / revenue risk between the host government and private developer and maintaining the appropriate balance between public amenity and project profitability will be core considerations. The section below discusses how different revenue models used for road PPPs seek to address these issues.

Competition issues can sometimes also arise in road projects (e.g. the private consortium may seek a government undertaking not to build competing roads).

Find below key topics on Road PPPs.

Payment Mechanism Options - How is Concessionaire to be paid

A key issue for roads PPPs is how the Concessionaire is to be paid and who is to bear the risks of traffic risk and revenue risk

  • traffic risk is the risk of how many vehicles will travel up and down the road

  • revenue risk is a factor of both traffic volumes/ toll rates and collection/ enforcement risk

Pure "Availability' based payment structures generally transfer neither of these risks to the private sector. "Shadow Toll" structures are seen as transferring traffic risk, but not revenue risk, and "Real-Tolled" structures are usually considered capable of transferring both risks.

  Real tolls Shadow tolls Availability/Performance base mechanisms
Features Road users pay for use of asset No actual tolls are collected from public Concessionaire paid for making road available for public use
    Concessionaire is paid by authority on road use – the more the road is used the more the concessionaire is paid Sometimes mixed with real tolls [e.g. Ireland] so that concessionaire pays a non-availability payment to authority for road or lane closures out of toll revenue.
   

Usually have banding mechanism, which applies different shadow toll payments to different levels of traffic

Common to have 4 bands:

  • Base Case: designed to service senior debt but not to provide return on equity
  • Higher bands: provide a return on equity
  • Top band: usually has a toll rate of zero to cap amount payable to concessionaire

Amount of deduction/ non-availability payment usually determined by reference to factors including:

  • length of project road that is unavailable
  • Number of lanes affected
  • Duration of unavailability
  • Time of day of unavailability
Advantages Zero cost to the Government Where environment is perceived to be hostile to real tolls, can introduce PPP structures  
  Government has fiscal space to fund other projects Prepare way for real-tolled roads in due course by cultivating an industry used to taking traffic risk Lower level of due diligence needed
    Multiple sources of funding can be drawn on by government Reduces risk on concessionaire – making project cheaper
    Mechanism of traffic risk transfer should reduce complexity of project and reduce level of due diligence required Removes emphasis on monitoring traffic flows during operational period
      No consumer resistance
Disadvantages High capital construction costs mean that projects traffic volumes often considered an insufficient revenue stream to meet debt service and equity return for sponsors No revenue generation device – total cost of project falls on public purse No revenue generation device – total cost of project falls on public purse
  Often some form of subsidy/ very long concession period (see grant funding below) If traffic volumes are significantly in excess of forecasts, government may find itself paying more “toll” than it budgeted for. [This happened in Portugal] Concessionaire is not concerned how much traffic volume there is and so do not transfer traffic or revenue risk.
  Reluctance by investors to become involved – costs will be higher to reflect higher risks    
  Potential consumer resistance to paying for road use and how to mitigate this    

Hybrids/ Typical Added Features

Any of these mechanisms may be supplemented by various performance-based criteria, such as:

  • safety improvements must be created

  • rid-quality thresholds to be met

  • rut-depth values not to be exceeded

  • skid-resistance tests must be met

  • loss of road surfacing must not exceed agreed thresholds

  • services must be delivered (e.g. sign cleaning, grass cutting)

  • reductions in end to end journey times

The grant funding authority may choose to support the project with a grant to reduce the level of senior debt required to complete the road and/ or operation grants to assist with ongoing operational costs. In some jurisdictions, such as UK, Government can get favorable balance sheet treatment of grants by balancing payment mechanism with sufficient demand risk.

An availability-based mechanism could be adopted that includes scope for increased payments for higher traffic volumes to compensate for increased maintenance.

Another consideration is whether to have variable toll rates for different types of vehicles and discounts for local vehicles.

One way to share risk is to include a ‘gain sharing’/ revenue sharing mechanism in real-tolled projects to share with concessionaire the benefit of higher than expected traffic volumes.

The road project authority could also retain revenue risk by having toll revenue paid over to it by the concessionaire – with concessionaire being remunerated by other means (e.g. shadow tolls).

This gives authority benefit of raising revenue to pay for project directly from users without transferring this risk to private sector.

Also read: Standard & Poor's Traffic Risk Studies

Key Risk Areas

Risk Issues/ comments

1. Toll collection technology

  • toll plazas
  • free flow systems (no plaza or physical barrier)

Which system most suitable

  • cost
  • system performance
  • flexibility
  • environmental impact
  • ease of use
  Challenge of free flow system is the collection/ enforcement risk and cost thereof
2. Traffic Risk – shadow and real-tolled projects Extensive studies required at various stages of procurement process

risk of not enough traffic

Few remedies available, other than lowering tolls to hope for increase of traffic volume
  Traffic guarantee – authority may grant a traffic guarantee – if actual levels of traffic fall below estimated threshold, payment is made by authority (may be for an initial period of concession)
  Impact of improvements to competing roads
3. Construction Issues
  • complexity of construction (does it involve bridge/ tunnel?)
  • how will cost overruns be borne by consortium members?
  • capacity for design and construct contractor to manage issue

Long-term risk of construction overruns

 

Maintenance structures

Is there to be a maintenance sub-contractor? How si this to be managed?

Control over road

Do local laws give third parties right to enter project road? Does any agency have right to prevent works from proceeding?

Change in law

Concessionaire will seek protection for changes to safety regulations General changes of law are usually borne by concessionaire – this can cause problems for the project’s viability

Events of default that give rise to termination right of authority

Concessionaire will want to limit these, and ensure that they are objective and clear compensation on termination also needs to be clear

Rights of step in

When can funders step in when project is failing before termination? Funders usually want this right established in a separate direct agreement.

Compensation on termination

UK and Ireland provide for zero compensation for termination for concessionaire default.

This is a concern for sponsors and financiers – and raises prospect of windfall gain for authority (free road)

Likely to be resisted by private sector for projects in developing countries – more likely to have risk sharing between parties

Force Majeure

UK and Ireland have very limited circumstances when compensation is paid on termination.

Developing countries unlikely to be able to pass as much risk to private sector.

Jurisdictional issues – these include:

  • Does authority have legal power to enter into concession contract?
  • Population and migration levels
  • Political will
  • Stability of country – political stability
  • Transparency of procurement process
  • Deal flow
  • Which authorities are involved in award process?
  • Insolvency regime
  • Impact of accounting treatment

Risk Matrices

Sample Bidding Document

Sample Agreements

  • Road Concession Agreement - Example 1 - concession agreement for design, construction, finance, operation and maintenance of a toll road prepared for country in Africa by international law firm (2006). Concessionaire receives income from tolls and Associated Facilities and Developments. Concessionaire agrees to pay a Concession Fee based upon share of surplus when a certain level of Shareholders’ IRR achieved.

  • Road Concession Agreement - Example 2 - concession agreement for development of upgrades to an existing road prepared for project in LAC by international law firm (2001). This document was extensively negotiated and is project specific. Care should be taken before replicating any of the provisions of the agreement - in particular those referred to in summary and annotation. The Concession envisages the creation of a Toll Regulator by statute but many issues are referred to an Expert. If the Regulator does not grant toll increases up to the Capped Toll Level as indexed in accordance with the Concession then Grantor has to pay balance. This may limit circumstances where the contract as drafted would be applicable.

  • Road Concession Agreement Example 3 - concession agreement for design, construction, finance, operation and maintenance of a toll road prepared for country in Africa.

  • Road Bridge Concession Agreement - Concession for the alleviation of congestion on an existing estuarial crossing by constructing an additional crossing and concessioning prepared by an international law firm for a country in Europe. Bidders had to identify in advance the income required to design construct and finance the second crossing and operate and maintain both. When the actual income from tolls equaled that amount after allowing for inflation the concession would terminate.

  • Road Infrastructure and Renewal in an Urban Area Concession Agreement - Honduras- Siglo XXI Project, San Pedro Sula (Proyecto Siglo XXI) (Spanish)- concession agreement for the design, construction, financing, managing, maintenance and transfer of the road infrastructure works of San Pedro Sula. (Concesión para el diseño, construcción, financiamiento, administración, mantenimiento y transferencia de las obras públicas de infraestructura vial de San Pedro Sula.)

  • Periphery Renewal Contract - Circuito Interior Bicentenario (IIC project) Mexico DF, Mexico (Spanish). Long term service provision contract for the urban improvement and integral maintenance of Circuito Interior Bicentenario, a periphery road for Mexico City

  • Roadway Around the Periphery of Sao Paolo City - Brazil (Spanish). Concession for a peripheral road in Sao Paolo, Brazil, which is primarily for transport of goods and cargo from the interior of the country to the port of Santos. The project is divided in several subsections; each section finances the construction of the next phase.

Standardized Documentation/ Publicly available Documentation for Specific Projects

Australia

West Gate Tunnel Project – Project Agreement between Transurban (an Australia based toll road operator with a substantial international footprint) and the State of Victoria in late 2017, for Transurban to design, construct, operate and maintain the upgraded West Gate Freeway and the new West Gate Tunnel (which connects several existing arterial roadways in the greater Melbourne area). The agreement is for a term of 28 years (including the design and construction phase) ending in 2045 and is structured on a Build Operate Transfer (“BOT”) model. It provides a useful example of a PPP infrastructure project where the demand / revenue risk is substantially passed onto the private sector through a tolling model. For the key features of the Project Agreement, read more...

Related project documents and more detailed project overview can be accessed on the Victorian Treasury website.

Canada
  • British Columbia - Golden Ears Bridge Crossing DBFO - DBFO Project Agreement + Concession Agreement and Ground Lease for design, build and financing of Golden Ears Bridge, BC, Canada. The Concession is for 16 years. The DBFO Contractor is paid Capital Payments and OMR Payments (for operations) and DBFO Contractor pays to the awarding authority a licence fee of $50,000,000 for the licence to use the Facility Lands. DBFO Contractor is not to charge tolls/ user charges - such right rests with the awarding authority.

  • British Columbia - Okanagan Lake Crossing Concession Agreement - Concession Agreement for design, build and financing of a new crossing over the Okanagan Lake, BC, Canada together with operation and then decommission of the existing crossing. The Concession is for 30 years. The Concessionaire is paid availability payments and performance payments (linked to traffic volume, safety, user satisfaction - clause 31 and schedule 10). Concessionaire is not to charge tolls/ user charges. Concessionnaire is granted a non-exclusive licence to the Site.

  • British Columbia - Sea-to-Sky Highway Improvement DBFO - DBFO Concession Agreement for design, build and financing of improvements to Sea-to-Sky Highway in BC, Canada. The Concession is for 16 years. The DBFO Contractor is paid Total Performance Payments (based on Availability Payment, Vehicle Usage payment and Performance Incentives). DBFO Contractor is not to charge tolls/ user charges. Click on Project Schedules for other key documents.

  • Quebec - Autoroute 25 Concession Project (French) - Concession Agreement entered into in September 2007 for design, build and financing of rehabilitation and development and operation and maintenance of a portion of Autoroute 25 in Montreal, Quebec, Canada. The Concession is for a maximum of 35 years. The Private Partner collects tolls on behalf of Government which it then remits to the Government. The Private Partner is paid a construction fee + an availability fee + a fee based on the levels of revenue achieved, less certain deductions (see articles 29 and 30). Construction is due to be completed in 2011.

  • Quebec - Autoroute 30 Concession Project - Concession Agreement entered into in October 2008 for design, build operation, maintenance and repair (and financing) of Autoroute 30, which will provide a southern bypass of Montreal, Quebec, Canada. The Concession is for a maximum of 35 years. The Private Partner collects tolls on behalf of Government which it then remits to the Government. The Private Partner is paid a construction fee + an availability fee + a fee based on the levels of revenue achieved, less certain deductions (see articles 29 and 30).
Costa Rica
Honduras
  • Corredor Turístico (El Progreso-Tela, San Pedro Sula – El Progreso y La Barca – El Progreso) - Concession Agreement for the construction, operation, transfer, and maintenance of a 122-km, four-lane highway along the Atlantic side of Honduras ("touristic corridor") under a design, finance, build, operate, transfer (DFBOT) scheme (Spanish).

India

The National Highways Authority of India Act 1988 establishes the National Highways Authority of India (“NHAI”) to develop, maintain and manage national highways in India, as well as to collect tolls on several highways

The Public Private Partnership in National Highways: Indian Perspective discusses various issues relating to road PPPs in India including an overview of the regulatory framework and existing models of PPPs.

  • National Highways Authority of India - Model Concession Agreements - this is the latest version currently available on-line. 

  • Gomati Chauraha-Udaipur Project Toll Road – Concession Agreement between the NHAI and Shreenathji-Udaipur Tollway Private Limited (“Concessionaire”), a subsidiary of Sadbhav Infrastructure Projects Limited, to widen the Gomati Chauraha–Udaipur section of National Highway No. 8 (“NH-8”) in the State of Rajasthan. The agreement is for a term of 27 years (including the design and construction phase) and is structured on a DBFOT basis. The agreement is based on the model concession agreement published by the NHAI, but contains a number of bespoke provisions. The concession agreement adopts a tolling model, which shifts demand / revenue risk to the private sector. The government undertakes not to develop competing road projects, so as to further protect this project’s profitability. The concession agreement also contains an interesting profit-sharing mechanism which allows the government to receive some upside in the event of significant profits. For the key features of the agreement, read more...

United States

Further Reading and Resources

Download Page as PDF


Updated: October 11, 2021