Assessing Fiscal Implications
Photo Credit: Image by Pixabay
A proposed PPP project may be feasible and economically viable, and value for money analysis may show that the PPP is the best option to procure it. Nonetheless, the government also needs to decide whether the PPP project is affordable and fiscally responsible, given its fiscal constraints. Many governments have entered into PPPs not fully understanding their potential costs. This can create significant fiscal risk for governments (see Insufficient Funds). To avoid this pitfall, governments need to assess fiscal affordability when they appraise a PPP project so that they do not go to market with projects they cannot afford. Fiscal commitments can be either direct or contingent. For more on these concepts, see Types of Fiscal Commitments to PPPs. Governments need to assess the likely costs of both types of commitments. Once likely fiscal costs are identified, governments need to assess whether they are affordable. Controlling Aggregate Exposure to PPPs describes how governments can assess the affordability of those commitments. For example, by comparing annual cost estimates against the budget of the contracting authority, considering the impact on debt sustainability under various scenarios, or introducing specific limits on different types of PPP commitment. A World Bank note on managing fiscal commitments from PPPs (WB 2013b) provides an overview of typical types of fiscal commitments to PPP projects, and how these can be assessed. Direct fiscal commitments may include up-front capital contributions or regular payments by government such as availability payments or shadow tolls, as described in Types of Direct Payment Commitments to PPP Projects. Direct liabilities are payment commitments that are not dependent on the occurrence of an uncertain future event (although there may be some uncertainty regarding the value). Direct liabilities arising from PPP contracts can include: For more on types of payment commitments, see Public Financial Management Frameworks for PPPs. The nature of the government's direct commitments will be defined during the structuring process described in Structuring PPP Projects. This highlights the importance of a back-and-forth process between appraisal and structuring. The government should have an idea of the level and type of support that will be needed to make a project bankable to assess fiscal affordability before investing large amounts in project preparation. Fiscal limits set in appraisal can then inform further structuring efforts until the project converges on a structure that is both fiscally responsible and attractive to the market. In fact, the value of the direct fiscal commitments is often a key bid variable, as described in Managing PPP Transactions. This means the fiscal cost cannot finally be known until after the tender process is complete. During the appraisal stage, the value of the direct fiscal commitments required can be estimated from the project financial model, described in Assessing Commercial Viability. The value of these direct payment commitments is driven by the project costs and any non-government revenues. The value of the direct fiscal contribution required is the difference between the cost of the project (including a commercial return on capital invested) and the revenue the project can expect to earn from non-government sources such as user fees. The fiscal cost can be measured in different ways: In both cases, it is also helpful to estimate how the payments might vary—for example, they may be linked to demand, or be denominated in a foreign currency and so be subject to exchange rate changes. Irwin's paper on fiscal support to PPPs (Irwin 2003, 16–17 and Annex) provides more detail on measuring the cost of different kinds of fiscal support. Having estimated the cost of direct payment commitments, the government needs to decide if they are affordable. Controlling Aggregate Exposure to PPPs describes how some governments consider the affordability of direct payment commitments under PPPs—for example, this can include projecting current spending levels forward, or introducing specific limits on government payment commitments to PPPs. An OECD publication on PPPs (OECD 2008a, 36–46) provides a helpful overview. Contingent liabilities arise in well-designed PPP projects because there are some risks that government is best placed to bear. These risks should be defined throughout project structuring—see Structuring PPP Projects. Assessing the cost of contingent liabilities is more difficult than for direct liabilities, since the need for, timing, and value of payments are uncertain. Broadly speaking, there are two possible approaches, as described in the Infrastructure Australia guidance note for calculating the PSC (AU 2016b, 84–109): Scenario analysis is the simpler form of risk analysis, and gives a sense of the range of possible outcomes, but not their likelihood. In practice, most governments use scenario analysis, if anything, to assess the possible cost of contingent liabilities. A probabilistic approach requires more input data, and complex statistical analysis. In practice, only a few governments have used probabilistic analysis to assess a few types of contingent liabilities. Irwin's book on government guarantees (Irwin 2007) provides a comprehensive discussion of why and how governments accept contingent liabilities under PPP projects by providing guarantees, and how the value of these guarantees can be calculated. The following resources provide more guidance and example of how particular countries approach this problem: Defining and publishing a methodology for valuing contingent liabilities from PPPs is only part of the solution—implementing such methodologies in practice can be demanding. Governments may need to strike a balance between building capacity in risk analysis, and adopting sufficiently straightforward and simple approaches to this assessment that can be implemented in practice. Having estimated the cost of contingent liabilities, the government can assess whether they are affordable given fiscal constraints. For example, as described in Controlling Aggregate Exposure to PPPs, this could include considering the implications of PPP contingent liabilities in the context of overall debt sustainability analysis, or specific limits on PPP liabilities. A few countries, such as Indonesia, have introduced contingent liability funds to ringfence and budget for these liabilities. The EPEC publication on State Guarantees in PPPs (EPEC 2011a) also provides a helpful overview of different approaches to managing the fiscal implications of PPP contingent liabilities.
Assessing cost of direct fiscal commitments
Assessing the cost of contingent liabilities
Find in pdf at PPP Reference Guide - PPP Cycle or visit the PPP Online Reference Guide section to find out more.
Updated:
Related Content
INTRODUCTION
Page Specific DisclaimerVisit the PPP Online Reference Guide section to find out more.
PPP BASICS: WHAT AND WHY
Page Specific DisclaimerVisit the PPP Online Reference Guide section to find out more.
Featured Section LinksESTABLISHING THE PPP FRAMEWORK
Page Specific DisclaimerVisit the PPP Online Reference Guide section to find out more.
PPP CYCLE
Page Specific DisclaimerVisit the PPP Online Reference Guide section to find out more.
Identifying PPP Projects
Type of ResourceAppraising Potential PPP Projects
Type of ResourceStructuring PPP Projects
Type of ResourceDesigning PPP Contracts
Type of ResourceManaging PPP Transactions
Type of ResourceManaging PPP Contracts
Type of ResourceDealing with Unsolicited Proposals
Type of ResourceKey References - PPP Cycle
Type of Resource